THREE DECADES OF NAXALBARI
August 1997
(This
paper was presented at a seminar on the above topic held in Patna on 25 May
1996, Naxalbari Day. It was organized by various CPI(M-L) groups and mass
organizations. A Hindi version of it has also been published in "Samkalin
Bahas".)
25
May, 1967 was the day when the peasants of Naxalbari unfurled the banner of
armed revolt against their age-old exploitation and oppression and a peal of
'spring thunder' was heard all over India. This small spark spread a prairie
fire and there were a number of armed peasant revolts all over India. This set
in motion the open revolt of the revolutionaries in the CPM as Naxalbari struck
at the revisionist practice of the existing communist parties. The thunder of
Naxalbari found its echo in the towns with thousands of students and youth
rallying to the revolutionary cause. The ruling classes were frightened and let
loose counter-revolutionary violence. Thousands were thrown into jails and
tortured. The CPI(M-L) as part of the W. Bengal coalition government did not
hesitate in being part of this reign of terror.
But
the 'spark' was not to die. Its revolutionary message spread far and wide all
over India. The question of armed revolution came to the fore with a bang.
Naxalbari no longer remained an obscure place in West Bengal but became a
slogan. Today, all over India, wherever one finds the downtrodden rebelling
against hunger and inequality, for dignity and livelihood, for their rights and
liberty, wherever there is a first rising in revolt, one finds the slogan of
'Naxalbari Lal Salam' (Red Salute to Naxalbari). Naxalbari is indeed a great
milestone in the Indian communist movement, nevertheless, we yet have a long,
tortuous path to traverse.
"Every
step of real movement is more important than a dozen programmes", wrote
Marx and indeed it was the peasant revolt in Naxalbari which again proved it to
be so. This revolt came as a bolt of lightning to strike at the programme and
practice of the two revisionist communist parties - CPI(M) and CPI. It was a
living criticism of the practice of these parties - their support to the
so-called progressive Nehruvian policies, their thesis of "peaceful
transition" and parliamentarism.
The
theoretical propositions and theses propounded in the wake of Naxalbari came as
a natural reaction to the policies of parliamentary cretinism and opportunism
of the revisionist parties. Left adventurism and anarchism became dominant in
the days to come, though, of course, there were some shining examples of mass
movements and a few exceptions. Lenin had rightly observed that anarchism often
visited the working class movement as a punishment for its opportunism. The
line of individual annihilation, disregard of open and mass forms, later
dependence on the petty-bourgeois intellectual, disregard for working class
actions, defaced this movement that came to be named after Naxalbari - the
Naxalite movement. Whether it be in the formulations on guerilla-war, the war
of liberation or in its international-aspects, like, the movement being part of
the 'Great Proletarian Cultural Revolution' of China or a part of a movement in
the "era of final and total collapse of imperialism". etc., we find
that there were grave deviations from Marxist-Leninist teachings. Though the
step of real movement Naxalbari was of real significant programmatic moment, as
we shall see, the ideological cloak that it wore had many a hole.
Here
are some propositions and theses which had wide currency and commanded great
influence in the days following Naxalbari --
In
his political-organisational Report at the 1970 Party Congress of the CPI(M-L)
Com. Charu Mazumdar (CM) called for individual annihilation and defended the dependence
on the petty-bourgeois intellectual. He held that "the battle of
annihilation is both a higher form of class struggle and the starting-point of
guerrilla war". This report is permeated by the anarchist idea of the use
of excitative terror to arouse the masses. The disregards for mass forms led to
CM's assertions that 'mass organization and mass movement increase the tendency
towards open and economist movement.' (Liberation, Dec 1996).
The
dependence upon the petty-bourgeois intellectual alongwith disregard for mass
forms led to the emphasis on ididvidual terrorism - "The method of forming
a guerrilla unit has to be wholly conspiratorial .. This conspiracy should be
between intellectuals and on a person to person basis. The petty-bourgeois
intellectual comrade must take the initiative in this respect as far as
possible. He should approach the poor peasant who, in his opinion, has the most
revolutionary potentiality, and whisper in his ears: "Don't you think it a
good thing to finish off such and such a jotedar(Big Landowner)?" this is
how the guerillas have to be selected and recruited singly and in secret, and
organised into a unit. "(CM-Liberation 1970) At the international level,
the movement was much influenced by the formulations of the Ninth Congress of
the CPC. Lin Piao, who incidentally was later reviled, became a great authority
- the Declaration of the revolutionaries of the CPI(M) talked of "Comrade
Mao Tse Tung's great blue-print for world revolution" "presented in a
concentrated form by Comrade Lin Piao". The Ninth Congress had decreed
that it was the era of Mao Tse Tung thought, the era of rapid and total
collapse of imperialism", the era of victory of socialism. Even the advent
of Soviet Social imperialism was seen as an episode in the final downfall of
imperialism! There were strange, impulsive extrapolations from all this and
overestimation of one's forces, the hallmark of Left adventurism, ruled the
day. It was held that "in this era (of MTT) it is impossible to repeat the
performances of Hitler and Mussolini, it is impossible to launce a savage
attack on the revolutionaries" (CM). No wonder then that 1975 was set as
the time by which India would be liberated. We, of course, do not appraise this
estimation of liberation by 1975 just by its episodic failure. Had this
estimation been founded on a proper appraisal of the disposition of class
forces, nationally and internationally, then it would have been justified or at
worst a small mistake even if it met with failure. Revolutionary enthusiasm
does not snivel at episodic failures, nor does it begin with the prospect of
certain success. But, the whole affair was based on an overestimation of
forces, nationally and internationally. Further, this estimate was based on a
simple calculation and a gradualist, linear view of the development of the
revolutionary process. (Incidentally, even today M-L groups take such a view,
the only difference being that they think that liberation would be achieved in
the distant future). This is how Com. Charu Mazumdar put it - "The idea of
today's armed struggle was first born in the mind of one man. That idea has now
filled the minds of ten million people. If the new revolutionary consciousness,
born only in 1967, can permeate the minds of ten million people in 1970, why is
it impossible then for those ten millions to rouse and mobilize the 500 million
people of India in a surging people's war by 1975." No wonder then that
with an incident of rifle-snatching at Magurjan in W. Bengal, it was announced
that the People's Liberation Army had started marching.
These
are but some snippets which give a rough idea of the dominant practice of those
days, such were the ideas which followed in the wake of Naxalbari many of which
have been jettisoned in theory and the movement has made some self-criticism in
practice. We must take note of the grave deviations
from M-L theory when we examine any idea which claims to be the heritage of
Naxalbari, draws upon the aura of Naxalbari.
We
said that Naxalbari was a living criticism of the practice and programme of the
revisionist parties. This criticism stood out glaringly in the case of the
agrarian programme of these parties. After 1947 the Indian state embarked upon
a policy of agrarian reforms and enacted a number of laws like the Zamindari
Abolition Act(ZAA) etc. The CPI found these policies progressive and extended
support to them at best railing and ranting at their non-implementation or
other "ill-effects". Let us examine one of the key measures, the
Zamindari Abolition Act. In 1946, the Congress had proclaimed in its election
manifesto that it will definitely abolish the intermediaries. Between the
direct producer and the state there were a number of intermediaries who lived
upon the land, ostensibly to help collect revenue for the state. They sponged
upon the actual cultivator who was thus subjected to rack-renting. Abolition of
intermediaries had become necessary and the pressure of mass movements from
'below' was there too. This was to be done in favour of the landlords as the
Indian state by its very nature could only do this. Through the ZAA the state
exerted pressure on the landlords to take up farming on a capitalist basis. In
this process the zamindars were given huge amounts as compensation and through
various subterfuges they were allowed to resume their land for
self-cultivation. They were encouraged to dispossess their raiyats. That is why
we find large scale eviction of the raiyats following Zamindari abolition. Of
course, these reforms did not per se lead to capitalist farming,
but the pressure was there and given other factors could and did lead to this.
At the same time the ZAA by abolishing intermediaries brought the raiyats into
direct relations with the state, in the process encouraging a numerous
sub-stratum of rich peasants who were freed from the burden of overlordship.
Similarly,
the Ceiling Acts were again a measure intended to act at a spur to changeover
to capitalist cultivation. These reform laws also carried a proviso which
excluded capitalist-type farms and plantations form the purview of reform. We
can also see that between every announcement and legislation and every
legislation and implementation, there was a big time gap so that the big
landowners could rearrange their landholdings and operations, and evict their
raiyats, bataidars etc. This way they were pressurized to take up
self-cultivation instead of living upon old-type or pre-capitalist type rent
(Just an announcement by Laloo Yadav of a new Bataidari Law in favour of
share-corppers led to the eviction of a large number of bataidars). Thus the
state pressurized the landlords to take-up modern cultivation. This was done in
favour of the landlords and the emerging rich peasantry and by bringing untold
suffering and misery for the rest of the peasantry.
In
order to dispel all sorts of wrong notions regarding land reforms we must have
an understanding of the way capitalist development takes place in agriculture.
As Lenin has pointed out capitalist development in agriculture can take place
through either of the two paths - 1) the bourgeois - landlord path, and 2) the
path of peasant reforms, i.e., by breaking-up the pre-capitalist relations in a
revolutionary manner by undertaking confiscation of the land of the landlords
and general redistribution of land. Lenin called the former path, the Prussian
path. He observed, "The former implies the utmost preservation of bondage
and serfdom (remodeled on bourgeois lines), the least rapid development of the
productive forces, and the retarded development of capitalism; it implies
infinitely greater misery and suffering, exploitation and oppression for the
broad mass of the peasantry and consequently, also for the proletariat."
(Agrarian Programme of the RSDLP, CW - 13) Lenin held that the Russian
Octobrist Programme after the 1905 revolution, the programme of the reactionary
landlords, definitely took the stand of capitalist development, it was
economically progressive. It was reactionary not because it sought to
perpetuate any pre-capitalist relations but because it stood for the 'Prussian
path' the path of slow, painful capitalist evolution (one which was detrimental
to the interests of the peasantry and also to the proletariat). This path means
the slow, gradual severing of pre-capitalist relations and their remodeling on
bourgeois lines. But it is also a path of capitalist evolution in agriculture,
one which brings untold miseries for the peasant masses. It is clear from above
that capitalist evolution in Indian agriculture has taken place through the
Prussian path. It is important to note that it also ushers in capitalist
relations. The CPI and CPI(M), found the state fostering capitalism and hence
called these policies progressive. They followed in the wake of the ruling
classes and supported the Nehruvian policies. The significance of Naxalbari
precisely lay in stressing the second path, the path away from reformism, the
path of realising the agrarian demands in a revolutionary way. It squarely put
forth the question of land with state power, Com. Charu Mazumdar
dubbed the overemphasis on land seizure as 'economism' - it was a radical break
with the past, away from the path of rallying around bourgeois-landlord
reforms. The land question was made a part of revolutionary politics. If we
view this question only from the point of view of development of productive
forces then we can never make a revolutionary presentation of the question. As
we said that the CPI and CPI(M) found that the landlord-bourgeois reforms of
the state fostered development of the productive forces, lent this process
their support and jettisoning revolutionary politics got incorporated into the
state. CPI(M-L) 'Liberation' is also following in the footsteps of the CPI
& CPM. In its programme passed at its 5th. Congress it says - ".the
principal contradiction (is) between feudal remnants and the board Indian
masses, for the feudal remnants remain the biggest stumbling block on the road
of free and rapid development of productive forces in the country". Since
the Indian state fosters the development of productive forces, it has taken
steps to gradually sever the pre-capitalist or feudal relations through its
various programmes.., 'Liberation' will help hasten this process, will take
forward this 'progressive' programme. CPI(M-L) 'Liberation' itself confesses
that it has taken up the positions of the CPI(M) and it proposes to form
governments as "instruments of struggle". And all this after the
lessons of Naxalbari, after Naxalbari has shown that a revolutionary posing of
the agrarian question must abjure the path of supporting bourgeois-landlord
reforms.
Hitherto
in the above passages we had been dealing mainly with the predominant trend of
the Naxalite movement. There was the UCCRI(M-L) trend, the Dakshin Desh (the present MCC), the
Andhra group, and all of them criticized one or the other aspect of the
left-adventurist movement. On the whole these groups made a one-sided appraisal
of phenomena and their criticism was not comprehensive. For all the talk of
'authority' by the then united CPI(M-L), the movement badly lacked a center
commanding ideological influence, which, in the days to come showed up in the
fragmentation of the movement.
This
one-sidedness and lack of a center equipped with Marxist-Leninist theory was
further confounded by the difficult process of cognition of the Indian reality.
The slow, gradual changes brought through the 'Prussian Path', the remodeling
of some pre-capitalist relations along bourgeois lines has indeed made the
cognition of this reality difficult. This process of cognition shows
interesting turns on the question of the principal contradiction. From
"the contradiction between feudalism and the broad Indian masses" as
the principal contradiction at the beginning of the movement to the formulation
of the "contradiction between imperialism and the oppressed peoples"
as the principal contradiction, the various naxalite groups have at one time or
the other reached this or that conclusion. Today some groups hold that
feudalism is a spent force and identify imperialism as the main enemy. They
make light of the 1970 programme which holds that the contradiction between
feudalism and the broad Indian masses to be the principal contradiction. It takes
the view that an attack on feudalism also weakens imperialism. This rested on
the premise that feudalism was the main prop of imperialism in our country.
Imperilism at first allies with the feudal ruling classes and they serve as its
main social prop. Though this holds good for the past it need not hold good for
all time. It is only one manifestation of imperialism's characteristic of
political reaction and domination and is undoubtedly true in some given
historical condition, but we cannot absolutise and universalize it. That is why
Lenin in his polemics with Kautsky pointed out - "The characteristic
feature of imperialism is precisely that it strives to annex not only agrarian
territories but even the most highly industrialized regions." (Imperialism ; CW-22, pp. 268-69) Those
groups which could sense the changes, took note of the imperialist fostered
capitalist growth, marked out imperialism as the main enemy.
This
process of cognition in the movement is more the result of learning from one's
own experience rather than any scientific analysis based on Marxism-Leninism.
Take the principal contradiction affair - it was only when it was realised that
attacks on feudalism were not weakening imperialism, that new formulations
started emerging.
This
"learning from one's own experience" by the leaders is a peculiar
inversion of the Leninist tactics of letting the masses learn from their own
experience. No wonder then that one finds the worst 'bowing to spontaneity'.
The whole movement is thus unable to carry forward working-class politics, is
unable to provide leadership through foresight, but can only follow in the wake
of events. If the '70s bowed to the passionate indignation of the
petty-bourgeois intellectual, which found its reflection in the terroristic
line of individual annihilation, the '90s bow to the mass economic struggles.
The 'annihilation line' was jettisoned by the various groups one by one in
accordance with their own level of cognition. It is interesting to note that
while Com. C.P. Reddy at the very beginning subjectively divided the
revolutionary process in India into stages and held that it was presently the
stage of the 'Resistance Struggle', it is only recently that some M-L groups
have arrived at this formulation.
This
worship of spontaneity leads to indifference towards political tasks. Take the
proponents of 'Resistance Struggle'. They impose upon the masses stages of
struggle in a subjective manner and their theses are based on some belief in a
gradualist, additive approach (remember, a complete 'stage' and not only just
one aspect - the practical-economic of the movement). This stage is supposed to
be limited to economic issues and we have been told that this stage doesn't
directly involve the question of state power. But then it is held that this
does not mean that the issues raised at this stage do not involve the question
of state power. It has been argued that since in the course of their
practical-economic fight the masses come up against state power it becomes
related to the question of state power i.e. their economic struggle (for land,
wages etc.) leads them to politics. This is exactly as the Russian economists
of yore argued. While criticizing Economism, Lenin wrote of the communist party
that it represents "the working class not in the latter's relations to
only a given group of employers, but in its relation to all classes of modern
society, to the state as an organised political force". (What is to be
done?) But with the theory of stages - at present that of the resistance struggle
- some contingents of the communist movement reduce themselves to the status of
economic organizations, to militant trade-unionism. The given economistic
formulation of tasks decreed by the theses of 'resistance struggle' negates the
Leninist view and does not promote such methods of struggle and forms of
organization that can enable the masses to have their own political experience
through which they can be brought to the revolutionary front. This certainly
cannot be done if we reduce our whole movement to the practical-economic. And
for this, as Lenin observed, propaganda and agitation are not enough. It is
believed that the political education of the working class and the toilers can
be fulfilled by raising their consciousness through propaganda only. But there
can be no political education of the masses apart from drawing them into the
political struggle. As Lenin observed ". There can be no political
education except through political struggle and political action. Surely it cannot be
imagined that any sort of study circles or books etc., can politically educate
the masses of workers if they are kept away from political activity and
political struggle.
(CW 4/P228). But our proponents of resistance struggle want to keep the fight
within the boundary of enonomism - land, wages, developmental work etc. and
talk of raising political consciousness in the abstract. The lack of political
struggle and education shows up most pathetically during elections when the
masses in their areas of struggle turn a deaf ear to calls for boycott and
instead support one or the other ruling-class party.
This
lack of politics shows up at its worst in the dealing of the peasant question.
Naxalbari had tried to pose this question in a revolutionary manner but today
this has been forgotten. This question is understood by the working class
party, i.e., the communist party, as part of its policy to win state power. But
today this question is brushed aside, the question of achieving and
consolidating the dictatorship of the proletariat is disregarded and
implementation of 'land to the tiller' per se is declared to be the
touchstone of revolutionary activity. We find that party literature in India is
replete with accounts of land seizures - mostly 'ceiling surplus' land vested
with the government or in the possession of individual landowners. As a measure
of reform, as something which brings immediate relief to the toiling masses, it
is all very fine, but it is described as the class struggle. Everywhere this
fight for land is described as an anti-feudal fight. We may ask, where is the
politics of the affair? Where is the politics of Naxalbari - the formulation of land
with state power as opposed to the agrarian reforms of the
ruling classes and the support extended to them by the revisionist communist
parties? A passionate preoccupation with land seizures does not make for
communist politics. (The revisionist communist parties also seize land and even
the state distributes land). For where are the policies which would ensure the
hegemony of the proletariat? All political questions - question of liberty
(curtailment of rights),quastion of attitude towards various ruling class
policies, various movements of different sections of the proletariat and
toilers, anti-imperialist fights, are relegated to the background for 'land to
the tiller' is the basic slogan and even that perhaps means distributing
ceiling surplus land! ('Land to the tiller' is not interpreted as meaning
general redistribution). In the event of absence of proletarian politics and
Bolshevik preparation for state power, the net effect would be that the M-L
parties would start behaving like militant NGOs (voluntary agencies) fighting
for the implementation of government programmes of ceiling surplus land,
minimum wages, developmental work etc. or else get bogged down in
parliamentarism (some M-L groups in their propositions hold that implementation
of government programmes and developmental work is an important component of
their programme during the stage of the 'resistance struggle').
This
militant NGOish behaviour as a result of lack of politics shows up in the talk
and practice of village level democracy or 'jan panchayats'. Lenin
dubbed such democracy without conquest of state power as 'wash basin' democracy
which rests content with minor, local and unimportant issues amounting to a
lack of action affecting the economic system as a whole, the state structure as
a whole. It diverts attention from the central task of overthrow of bourgeois
rule. Today when the 'policies' framed by the state affects all aspects of our
life which has been drawn closely together by the rule of capital, when
economic life is 'manipulated' at metropolitan centers of world imperialism and
directly affects the people, resting content with village level democracy, its
glorification, means discounting the political struggle, the struggle against
class rule. It is argued that all this breaks the semi-feudal production
relations - it might be so, you are aiding and accelerating an ongoing process
- but, as for communist politics, all this is far from it. At different places
and if different ways there has been an expansion of the movement but what
about proletarian politics as opposed to bourgeois politics? It has been
relegated to the background. An approach which given pride of place to local
issues and isolated work inevitably leads to the neglect of class politics as a whole. Lenin held that -
"The predominance of isolated work is naturally connected with the
predominance of the economic struggle" (CW 4/p.367) (It is interesting to
note that many comrades in the movement opine that we have fought
"feudalism but not imperialism").
One-sided
appraisal of phenomena and narrow empiricism are among the other 'outstanding'
features that have characterized our movement. It is interesting to note that
many of our leaders come to realise that India had a parliamentary system which
accorded democratic rights, however restricted, during the emergency. Truly for
them "negation was determination". They argued thus : surely there
must have been some democratic rights which have been curbed now. So it took
the emergency to realise this! What can one say about such "leaders"?
This
one-sided appraisal of phenomena shows up glaringly in the different approaches
to parliament. From the correct appraisal that parliament is a pig-sty, a
talking-shop and historically obsolete, some contingents raise the slogan of
election-boycott and what is worse, have turned this slogan into a shibboleth
to demarcate themselves from other groups. Here is Lenin's appraisal - "
revolutionary tactics cannot be built on a revolutionary mood a one. It is very
easy to show one's "revolutionary" temper merely by hurling abuse at
parliamentary opportunism or merely by repudiating participation in parliaments,
its very ease, however, cannot turn this into a solution of a difficult, a very
difficult problem." Again." even if only a fairly largeminority of the industrial workers,
and not 'millions' and 'legions', follow the lead of the lead of the catholic
clergy and a similar minority of rural workers follow the landowners and kulaks
- it undoubtedly signifies that parliamentarianism in Germany has not yet politically outlived
itself, that participation in parliamentary elections and in the struggle on
the parliamentary rostrum is obligatory on the party of the
revolutionary proletariat specifically for the purpose of educating the
backward strata of its won class, and for the purpose of awakening and
enlightening the undeveloped, downtrodden and ignorant rural masses. Whilst you
lack the strength to do away with bourgeois parliaments and every other type of
reactionary institution(we have forgotton all about fraction work, of working
within reactionary organisations -- "whereever the masses are found"
-- but seek only to perpetuate our sects.), you must work within them because it is
there that you will still find workers who are duped by priests and stultified
by the conditions of rural life, otherwise you risk turning into nothing but
wind bags." (Leftwing Communism) (It is interesting to note that even this
essentially political slogan is being sought to
be reduced to the economic level - boycott for dams, for roads etc. this is
because these groups from their long years of experience have come to realise
that the boycott does not work). On the other hand, those who found that
parliament had political relevance gave one-sided emphasis on it. So much so
that they took it to be their duty to take part in every parliamentary exercise
and fell prey to parliamentary cretinism. They started appraising politics
through parliamentary spectacles and not in terms of the class struggle. No
wonder they tagged themselves on to this or that progressive, backward-caste,
anti-authoritarian party, placing their politics at the service of these
parties. Ironically, even the 'boycott' camp has fallen a prey to this
parliamentary cretinism - look at the support the BSP garnered from the after
its success at the 1993 U.P. elections. The Naxalbari movement was not only
living criticism of the revisionist policies of peaceful transition and
parliamentarism but also gave a shining example of the application of the
Leninist principle of attack on compromising parties, i.e., parties which
reconcile the working class and other toiling masses to bourgeois rule. This
movement made a telling attack on the compromising parties, the CPI &
CPI(M) and gave a revolutionary, leftward shift to politics. But today the
various contingents of the M-L camp have jettisoned all this by their politics
of tailism (behind Janata Dal. BSP etc.).
This
one-sided appraisal of the parliamentary system has led to a rift in the
movement, though, Marxism-Leninism holds that in this era of imperialism
extra-parliamentary struggles are more important and decisive and the question
of boycott does not warrant a split. From boycott to the bog of
parliamentarism, the about-turn in the case of 'Liberation' has its own
interesting tale.
The
tendency of the leaders of the Naxalite movement to learn from their own
experience and their worship of spontaneity shows a complete lack of
theoretical concern. It leads to empiricism and pragmatism. The influence of
pragmatism shows up glaringly in the case of the parliamentary practice of
'Liberation' which takes resort to any unprincipled election alliance (For
instance, with the Samata Party in Bihar).
This
worship of spontaneity is one of the important factors which reinforces the
fragmentation in the revolutionary communist movement with various contingents
at different levels of experience not comprehending and appreciating one
another. This stems from a lack of theoretical concern
which forces practice to grope in the dark. All the wrong ideas about
parliament, individual annihilation etc. only show the bankruptcy on the
theoretical front. Pragmatism and empiricism is manifested in the growing
preoccupation with issues like women's oppression, environmentalism, national
struggles, all sorts of fads trumped up by imperialism to the exclusion of
class politics, of a fight against class rule. All these issues are dealt in an
abstract, one-sided manner without linking them up with the historic tasks of
the working class, of the cause of socialism. An economistic formulation of
tasks, of concerns with issues local, not affecting the state structure as a
whole, accords well with such a presentation of problems of various sections.
More, it threatens to drag the movement into the mire of reformism.
There
are certain groups which see things in a 'broader' perspective, want to
intervene in the political process and struggle to influence state policies.
But, in their case, lack of a Marxist-Leninist presentation of tasks inevitably
means following in the wake of the evolutionary path of capitalism, the
bourgeois - landlord or variant of Prussian path being followed in India. Thus
PCC takes 'reservations' to be the touchstone of revolutionary politics in
India. Reservations are nothing but state incorporation and part of the process
of the slow evolution of a small strata of bourgeoisie and petty - bourgeoisie
from among the downtrodden castes. The question is not posed in a revolutionary
manner at all. The question is not how a microscopic minority becomes part of
the mainstream of official society but how the vast majority of the downtrodden
will constitute itself as a official society.
The
agrarian movement made a shift to the left with Naxalbari. The Naxalite
movement had for its social base the agricultural proletariat and the poor
peasantry. In terms of caste the overwhelming majority of these sections
belonged to the oppressed castes. Fight against social oppression, for dignity,
fuelled this movement. With the penetration of commodity - money relations, the
dissolution of 'jajmani' relations, this oppression does not appear as 'given'
in their relations and social oppression becomes the target of struggles.
The
slow, gradual evolutionary path of Indian capitalism carries with it the
possibility of meeting such demands (what some groups describe as
"breaking semifeudal relations"). This process serves as a rationale
for the local existence of M-L groups and provides them the social basis. The
concern with growth of capitalism, of the growth of productive forces leads to
a non-political economistic formulation. In as much as old issues are dying
away, one can find a growing preoccupation with developmental (!) work. This lends the
whole movement an NGOish colour.
The
increasing recognition of the growth of capitalism in India comes in a variety
of ways - the slow, evolutionary process which has brought untold miseries with
capitalist growth is met by theses of distorted capitalism, neo-colonial
capitalism and so on. Feudalism was the target and capitalism, the way out, the
'progressive' force in our theses. So, when it was observed that capitalist
growth brought misery, destitution, ruin there was a cry of disbelief. It was
thought that capitalism meant growth, development. Marx had shown that
capitalism inevitably meant prosperity and concentration of wealth at one pole
and misery at the other. But our comrades had drawn a mental picture of a
pretty capitalism - a capitalism without misery, oppressionet al. For
them capitalist growth meant prosperity for all. The infamies of capitalism
were also dubbed as semi-feudalism. Let us suppose that we have distorted
capitalist growth, neo-colonial capitalism and so on. Now this not only means the growth
of productive forces in a certain manner but also the growth of certainclasses - the bourgeoisie, the
middle strata and the proletariat. Perhaps distorted capitalism has produced a
distorted proletariat. Perhaps we cannot enter into a fight against the ruling
class with this proletariat? Naxalities who are obsessed with the growth of
productive forces can only see distortions in this capitalist growth but not
the growth in the strength of our class - the proletariat. There is no talk of
class-outlook and class analysis. The great Chinese revolution was led by the
proletariat working under comprador-bureaucrat capital. But we in India will
first ensure ourselves a pure proletariat, a pure capitalism and then go on to
make a pure proletarian revolution!
Let
us take Bihar, one of the most backward states of India. The Naxalite movement
there is a practical reminder of a shift in class forces - the occupancy
raiyats, who had a direct fight against the zamindars formed the social base of
the All India Kisan Sabha or the old communist
movement, while we have the increasingly assertive rural proletariat,
semi-proletariat (poor peasantry) as the social base of Naxalism. The changed
correlation of class forces, the ongoing class struggles, which show the breach
of interests between the peasant bourgeoisie on the one hand and the rural
proletariat and semi-proletariat (poor peasant) on the other, impel us to
recognize the need for the socialist revolution. The fight today is mainly
against capitalism, against imperialism. Imperialist capital today operates
through Indian capital, its main prop (it goes without saying that all feudal
remants must be actively fought).
Much
is made of the path illumined by Naxalbari. The path is supposed to be the
Chinese path. From CM's formulations on base area, guerilla war to PLA
formation at Magurjan with the snatching of a rifle, we have come a long, long
way after three decades. Today even the most well-equipped struggling armed
groups hesitate to call their areas of operation base areas and have to take
resort to formulations like resistance struggle and there is no talk of a People's Liberation Army at present. We do not want
to go into all this here, it is outside the scope of this paper, but one thing
is certain, the last word on the question of the path has not been said yet.
Another important thing to note is that the path of Chinese Revolution is not a
synonym for armed revolution. It goes without saying that in as mush as one
wants to build a revolutionary party one must try to know and assimilate the
'last word' in the world communist movement as Lenin put it, we must learn from
other revolutionary movements. But we must not make caricatures. It may be
noted here that questions over the Chinese path do not question the need for the armed
squads operating today.
Today,
when we are discussing Naxalbari after three decades, we must bring the question of state power on the agenda of the day.
For this, we must establish proletarian politics. If we want to make
revolution we must not get bogged down in economism and pragmatism, we must
formulate our political tasks and this cannot be done by bowing to spontaneity.
If we want to provide leadership we must equip ourselves with communist theory,
groping in the dark is bowing to spontaneity. Only then can we be said to be
following proletarian politics, only then can we stand at the head of events
and make a revolutionary formulation of different questions (caste, nationality
etc.) as Naxalbari had done in the case of the agrarian question. Today
economism predominates the fragmented movement. To take up the political tasks
we must try to build a united party of the proletariat. Only by ensuring the
leadership of the proletariat, the most advanced class facing the bourgeoisie
can we fight imperialism and capitalism. For this we must have a truly working
class party which must fight all petty-bourgeois deviations which have hitherto
defaced the movement. Today the increasing, assertion of the rural proletariat
under the banner of the Naxalite movement shows the changed correlation of
class forces. It shows that the demands of the proletariat must be met and only
the Socialist Revolution, the revolution which brings forth this class as the
ruling class, can do so by expropriating the expropriators and building
socialism.
- * END * -
No comments:
Post a Comment